Articoli correlati a Learning for Innovation in the Global Knowledge Economy:...

Learning for Innovation in the Global Knowledge Economy: A European and Southeast Asian Perspective - Brossura

 
9781841500850: Learning for Innovation in the Global Knowledge Economy: A European and Southeast Asian Perspective

Sinossi

In a study of the role of an "innovative milieu" in small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) in a knowledge-based economy, Konstadakopulos (European studies, U. of the West of England, Bristol) compares his survey results of SMEs in the UK with those in EU and ASEAN countries. Distributed in the US by ISBS. Annotation ©2004 Book News, Inc., Portland, OR (booknews.com)

Le informazioni nella sezione "Riassunto" possono far riferimento a edizioni diverse di questo titolo.

Estratto. © Ristampato con autorizzazione. Tutti i diritti riservati.

Learning for Innovation in the Global Knowledge Economy

A European and South-East Asian Perspective

By Dimitrios Konstadakopulos

Intellect Ltd

Copyright © 2004 Intellect Ltd.
All rights reserved.
ISBN: 978-1-84150-085-0

Contents

List of Tables,
List of Figures,
List of Abbreviations,
Introduction,
The origins of the research,
The main research questions,
The structure of the book,
Part I: The Embeddedness of Innovation in Regional Agglomerations,
Chapter 1: Fostering Innovation and Entrepreneurship,
Chapter 2: Technological Innovation Policies in the EU and ASEAN Economies,
Part II: The Empirical Comparative Analysis,
Chapter 3: Innovation in the West of England,
Chapter 4: Innovation in the Singapore-Johor Agglomeration,
Chapter 5: A Comparative Analysis of Patterns of Learning Behaviour and Co-operation in the West of England and Singapore-Johor,
Part III: Policy Lessons and Implications,
Chapter 6: The Relevance of the Economic, Political and Social Environments of Europe and South-East Asia,
Bibliography,
Appendix,
Index,


CHAPTER 1

Fostering Innovation and Entrepreneurship

1.1 Innovative Environments and the Importance of Proximity

Most firms in Europe and South-East Asia are well aware of the importance of innovation in achieving commercial success. However, relatively few firms are becoming innovators; most are content to adopt existing innovations. It seems that it is not only difficult to define precisely what innovation is, but also difficult to measure it, as it is not always directly reflected in the profitability of firms. It is more or less accepted that innovation means the creation of a better product or process. Dyson Ltd., based in the West of England, did exactly that when James Dyson and his research team designed a new type of high quality vacuum cleaner. This innovative product has been an outstanding commercial success, with sales of over £3 billion worldwide.

The problem of precisely defining innovation is compounded by the erroneous belief that the development of new products or processes adds to firms' costs and increases risks. On the contrary, it has been found that innovation brings far higher returns than ordinary business activities (Klomp and Leeuwen, 2001, p. 359). The suggestion that innovation-averse firms need to challenge their assumptions and start encouraging creativity and experimentation is supported by the findings of the present study. In addition, and most importantly, these firms must draw from the human capital of their region and learn from the best practice of their regional breakthrough innovators.

Of course, the nature of innovative activities varies markedly across trading blocks, as well as across areas belonging to the same block, owing to the different profiles of the areas' human capital in relation to education, age, occupation, wealth, and infrastructure endowment. For these reasons, within Europe and ASEAN some areas have more innovative companies than others. The South West of England, and in particular its north-eastern part - the West of England - has a large number of indigenous firms operating at the leading edge of technology, especially in advanced engineering, aerospace, telecommunications and electronics. Well-known indigenous world-class companies such as BAe (formerly British Aerospace), GNK-Westland, Messier-Dowty, Rolls Royce, Racal-Thorn, Rotork, Renishaw, and Smiths Industries, as well as many others, play a vital role in creating a dynamic regional economy. Alongside them, a number of multinational companies such as Hewlett Packard, Honda, Intel, Motorola, Lucent Technologies, and STMicroelectronics have moved in to exploit the region's knowledge and skilled workforce, its business atmosphere and reputation for innovation.

The Singapore-Johor cross-border area has a rather smaller number of indigenous high-technology companies and a large number of multinational companies operating in electronics, telecommunications, engineering and chemicals. Some of the indigenous companies, such as Aztech, Creative Technology and SingTel, have become world players in multimedia applications and telecommunications. It is nevertheless the presence of multinationals from Japan, the US and Europe, such as Compaq, Hewlett Packard, IBM, Matsushita, Motorola, NEC, Philips, Sony, Seagate, Siemens and STMicroelectronics to name a few, that has led to technological innovation in the area.

However, it is important to pay attention as much to the innovation processes, external sources of innovative ideas, and extent of innovative inter-firm linkages, as to the factors affecting the efficiency of regional or local economies. In addition, the institutionally embedded nature of the innovation process makes strong claims about the role of the regional/local context as a fundamental factor. In the following chapters we examine how far these propositions can be applied in practice to the West of England agglomeration and the Singapore-Johor cross-border area.


1.2 The Concept of the 'Innovative Milieu'

In order to understand the importance of regional innovation in the West of England and the Singapore-Johor cross-border area, it will be necessary to present the latest theoretical concepts found in economic and management disciplines. It should be pointed out that no major new theories on innovation and entrepreneurship have been developed since those of early economists such as Adam Smith, David Ricardo, Alfred Marshall and Joseph Schumpeter. Perhaps Galar's reminder of the ancient dictum natura horret vacuum - that there are no empty places waiting for new theories to be nested (2000, p. 288) - is appropriate in this context. However, during the last fifteen years, two concepts complementing the theories have emerged. These concentrate respectively on the innovative milieu(innovative environment), and on technological change.

In the late 1980s and early 1990s, a number of European economists, mainly from Italy, Switzerland, France and the UK, and known as the GREMI group (Groupement Européen des Milieux Innovateurs), elaborated on the theories of innovation and entrepreneurship and introduced the concept of the innovative milieu(milieu innovateur). The central theoretical assumption of the milieu approach is that the innovative milieu that is, the socio-economic environment of a region - is produced by the interactions of firms, institutions and labour. The GREMI group introduced the concept of the collective learning process, which increases the creativity and continuous innovation of firms belonging to that milieu (Camagni, 1991; 1995), although the concept has only recently been fully developed (Rabellotti, 1997; Bramanti and Ratti, 1997; Keeble et al, 1997 and 1999; Camagni and Rabellotti, 1997; Capello, 1999; Lawson and Lorenz, 1999; Helmsing, 2001). In the milieu, the process of learning is brought about by the activity of participating actors, the mobility of labour, and the interconnections between suppliers, customers and subcontractors. It is greatly assisted by face-to-face contacts between actors, and these are facilitated by geographical proximity.

Some fifty years ago, Alfred Marshall commented on the importance of such proximity for the steel industry in the 'industrial district' of Sheffield. However, the GREMI group points to different stages of development and different typologies of districts. They suggest that the evolution from clustering through to industrial districts and then towards milieux requires particular pre-conditions (Capello, 1999). The process of collective learning in an innovative milieu is attributed to the mobility of the local labour market, with the market supplying its own knowledge. Local cumulative knowledge may be grasped by local actors (particularly SMEs) and is the source of a dynamic comparative advantage. If these pre-conditions do not exist, what we have is simply a traditional, static Marshallian industrial district (Camagni and Rabellotti, 1997, p. 139). As Capello points out, when the local actors grasp collective learning and turn it into profits, then, and only then, does an innovative milieu emerge. The profits will partly remunerate the risks for innovation and uncertainty (Capello, 1999, p. 357).

The GREMI group attempts to explain the reasons why firms try to exploit this collective learning. This may depend on the willingness and capacity of local SMEs to absorb it, as well as on the awareness that such learning exists. In addition, the exploitation of collective learning is inversely related to the size of the firm (Capello, 1999, pp. 357-358).

In this respect, the collective learning process is seen to generate radical rather than incremental innovation. The firm's ability to produce a radical or breakthrough innovation is based on new knowledge, and scientific and managerial expertise, which stems from the historical process of cumulative know-how and learning processes (Rabellotti, 1997, p. 165; Gregersen and Johnson, 1997, p. 486). Once a firm needs to achieve a radical product innovation, it is more likely to exploit the existence of a large pool of skilled local labour, which brings with it accumulated knowledge. Process innovation requires incremental changes, and is the outcome of internal knowledge within each firm (Konstadakopulos, 1997). The same analogy applies to the size of the firm for the exploitation of collective learning (Rabellotti, 1997; Capello, 1999). A large and rather secretive firm is likely to exploit its internal resources, and most unlikely to participate in the socialisation process of creative knowledge. A small firm is more likely to tap into the region's collective learning and adapt it to its potentially different needs once the externality is present. According to recent findings in the Italian high-tech milieux, such firms are likely to be found in a high-technology milieu, characterised by the creation of new firms in which research ideas and technological innovations are shared and diffused (Capello, 1999; Bellandi, 2002). This process reduces the uncertainty inherent in technological innovation, and may allow the smaller firms to survive.

However, the capacity of local firms to exploit collective learning materialises when they can turn knowledge into a business idea (Capello, 1999, p. 357). Thus, either an emerging group of local entrepreneurs may willingly share this knowledge among themselves, or a local/regional institution could codify and diffuse such knowledge (Teubal, 1997, p. 1170; Helmsing, 2001, p. 303).

Geographical proximity also helps the establishment of horizontal linkages and activities between economic actors (particularly between SMEs) across sectors and technologies (Kirat and Lung, 1999, p. 30). However, it is also appropriate to mention here that the collective learning process involves not only technology but many other externalities derived from experience in joint marketing, project generation, management and organisation (Teubal, 1997, pp. 1183-4). Kamann effectively describes the intra-actor organisation and behaviour pattern at the milieu level:

The more activities actors transfer to other actors, the more activity chains of actors are interwoven and become interdependent; the more relationships are embedded into a distinctly homogeneous cognitive set of the network, the more synergy accrues, the more the network is entitled to bear the name 'innovative'. The more the territorial is prominent - both in the production links, the selection environment and cognitive embeddedness the more pronounced the role of the particular milieux will be.

(Kamann, 1997, pp. 376-377)


The socialisation of managers of SMEs is quite important here. This socialisation is known as the cafeteria effect, and is an important element in building a local entrepreneurial capacity. Interpersonal linkages through professional associations, clubs, families and other social organisations are vital channels for sharing and diffusing research ideas, technological innovations and expertise within the region.

The examples of Italian innovative milieux indicate that, after the establishment of the milieu, 'a positive feedback effect arises which reinforces the elements of continuity (stable labour market, stable inter-SMEs' linkages) and of dynamic synergies (interactive mechanisms leading to innovation)' (Capello, 1999). Stable labour relations mean that, although there is an apparent labour mobility within the milieu, there is hardly any inflow or outflow of skilled workforce that may destabilise it.

As noted earlier, the innovative milieu approach has incorporated and improved the Marshallian concept of the industrial district, but also parallels other recent theorisation and research traditions within the framework of the endogenous growth approach, such as local production systems and Post-Fordist flexible production specialisation. Moreover, the milieu approach puts forward two more elements that distinguish it from the above approaches: the collective learning process that enhances local creativity, and the reduction of the elements of uncertainty that are inherent in technological development and the innovative process (Camagni, 1991, p. 3).

So far, the GREMI group has not been able to define exactly what are the overall necessary conditions that make up an innovative milieu. For some time now, questions have been raised on how innovative milieux come into being (i.e. whether through luck or historical accident) and whether they represent a general model of regional development or a specialised model suited to highly unique circumstances (Bergman, 1991, p. 284). The above uncertainty has apparently led some of the GREMI researchers to attempt to distinguish between the endogenous, exogenous and techno-metropolitan milieu. They argue that the endogenous milieu arises around territorial networks of SMEs whose 'economic relations are rooted in history', under favourable culturalconditions. The exogenous innovative milieu arises from the establishment of subsidiaries of large companies in the area, while the third type of milieu arises from the proximity of metropolitan agglomerations and urbanisation effects (Kamann, 1997, pp. 380-381). One criticism of the innovative milieu concept is that it has only been used in high-technology areas, implying erroneously that innovativeness and high technology are the same thing (Lawson, 1997, pp. 11-12). Sternberg in particular has argued that the innovative milieu approach lacks operational feasibility, but the evidence to support this has been limited (Sternberg, 1996a, pp. 533-4). Storper argues that the GREMI group has never been able to specify the potential mechanism and process by which such milieux function, nor the economic rationalism by which milieux foster innovation. A tautology is apparent in that 'there is a circularity: innovation occurs because of a milieu, and a milieu is what exists in regions where there is innovation' (Storper, 1995, p. 203).

An examination of the literature also reveals that so far there are very few cases of regional agglomerations explained by the innovative milieu approach (Sternberg, 1996a, p. 533). However, it is important to point out that innovative milieux grow very slowly. Moreover, existing case studies undertaken by the GREMI group focus mainly on regions or agglomerations that are situated in the centre of Europe (Paci and Usai, 2000), and that are innovative and performing well. But the group has little to say about non-innovative milieux and what distinguishes them from innovative milieux, although more recently Capello has highlighted the importance of local pre-conditions that facilitate the exploitation of collective learning (Capello, 1999). Further criticisms concern the precise contribution that networks will eventually make to our understanding of regions (Bergman, 1991, p. 286), and the inadequate integration of the theory of networks into the region-oriented innovative milieu approach (Sternberg, 1996a, p. 532). The reason for such poor integration is that the innovative milieu approach is biased too heavily towards small firms and the incubator role of the milieu for innovation to be supported; it neglects some aspects of reality.

Notwithstanding the above criticisms, the GREMI group economists contribute substantially to our understanding of the process of regional development. They argue that the economic process is fundamentally about the creation of knowledge and resources. Both derive from the process of creativity of economic actors who are - at least in part - dependent on their milieu (Storper, 1995, pp. 203-204). Undoubtedly the innovative milieu approach has policy implications, given its capacity to enable decisions-makers to adopt measures that could create, duplicate or stimulate innovative milieux. Finally, the GREMI group links the concept of both the innovative milieu and the innovative network with the evolutionary theory of technological change proposed by Nelson, Winter, Freeman and Dosi, which acknowledges fully the importance of the learning process (Camagni, 1991, pp. 10-11; Capello, 1999).


(Continues...)
Excerpted from Learning for Innovation in the Global Knowledge Economy by Dimitrios Konstadakopulos. Copyright © 2004 Intellect Ltd.. Excerpted by permission of Intellect Ltd.
All rights reserved. No part of this excerpt may be reproduced or reprinted without permission in writing from the publisher.
Excerpts are provided by Dial-A-Book Inc. solely for the personal use of visitors to this web site.

Le informazioni nella sezione "Su questo libro" possono far riferimento a edizioni diverse di questo titolo.

Compra usato

Condizioni: molto buono
Former library book; may include...
Visualizza questo articolo

GRATIS per la spedizione in U.S.A.

Destinazione, tempi e costi

EUR 28,81 per la spedizione da Regno Unito a U.S.A.

Destinazione, tempi e costi

Risultati della ricerca per Learning for Innovation in the Global Knowledge Economy:...

Foto dell'editore

Konstadakopulos, Dimitrios
Editore: Intellect, Limited, 2004
ISBN 10: 1841500852 ISBN 13: 9781841500850
Antico o usato Brossura

Da: Better World Books, Mishawaka, IN, U.S.A.

Valutazione del venditore 5 su 5 stelle 5 stelle, Maggiori informazioni sulle valutazioni dei venditori

Condizione: Very Good. Revised ed. Former library book; may include library markings. Used book that is in excellent condition. May show signs of wear or have minor defects. Codice articolo GRP70143449

Contatta il venditore

Compra usato

EUR 6,05
Convertire valuta
Spese di spedizione: GRATIS
In U.S.A.
Destinazione, tempi e costi

Quantità: 1 disponibili

Aggiungi al carrello

Foto dell'editore

Konstadakopulos, Dimitrios
Editore: Intellect Ltd, 2004
ISBN 10: 1841500852 ISBN 13: 9781841500850
Nuovo paperback

Da: Mispah books, Redhill, SURRE, Regno Unito

Valutazione del venditore 4 su 5 stelle 4 stelle, Maggiori informazioni sulle valutazioni dei venditori

paperback. Condizione: New. New. book. Codice articolo ERICA82918415008526

Contatta il venditore

Compra nuovo

EUR 98,52
Convertire valuta
Spese di spedizione: EUR 28,81
Da: Regno Unito a: U.S.A.
Destinazione, tempi e costi

Quantità: 1 disponibili

Aggiungi al carrello